logo

41 pages 1 hour read

Joseph E. Stiglitz

The Price of Inequality

Nonfiction | Book | Adult | Published in 2012

A modern alternative to SparkNotes and CliffsNotes, SuperSummary offers high-quality Study Guides with detailed chapter summaries and analysis of major themes, characters, and more.

Themes

Vicious Circles

The Price of Inequality provides numerous examples of vicious circles, in which one action leads to another, which leads back to the first action. For example, as inequality increases, it leads to loss of opportunity, which in turn leads to more inequality. A second example is how inequality fosters instability, which in turn causes more instability, and so forth. This outcome is poor for the 99 percent, but it enriches the 1 percent. Therefore, other vicious circles work directly for the benefit of the 1 percent. For example, when banks take risks and get caught, they are fined, so they take more risks, get caught, and are fined, and so on.

Stiglitz also examines how the poor also get caught up in vicious circles, especially when they are anxious and stressed about not having the money they need. This stress can actually limit their ability to make good decisions that might improve their situations, and it actually makes bad situations worse.

These vicious cycles mirror Stiglitz’s larger argument that market failures caused by bubbles tend to recur with the same kind of dynamic. Banks, the Federal Reserve, and government policymakers missed the tech bubble in the 1990s, and they all missed the housing bubble in 2007. In both instances, the regulations imposed afterward tended to favor the very people and institutions that caused the problem in the first place. In the end, the 1 percent came out on top, the 99 percent came out on the bottom, and the 99 percent suffered most from the increased inequality.

Rent Seeking Causes Inefficiency

One of Stiglitz’s central arguments is that rent seeking, which is widespread in the US economy, causes inefficiency mostly because it causes poor allocation of resources. First, it leads to gaps between societal returns and private rewards. This gap is what sets up the wrong incentives. An example of market failure is when corporate governance allows leaders to do what is in their interest—to funnel money to themselves—instead of what is best for shareholders or society at large. This fuels the income gap and makes the economy even more inefficient. Also, with incentives, pay should be aligned with performance, but rent seeking has made that process inefficient: CEOs are paid bonuses whether their companies make money or make money fairly. CEOs are also allowed to take bonuses when their companies are involved with inappropriate practices like monopolies, restricting competition, or predatory lending. In short, incentives lead rent seekers to take the wealth from the 99 percent, not to create wealth.

Rent seeking also causes inefficiency because it leads to underutilized resources, especially labor. Because rent seekers take resources from the bottom 99 percent, they fail to pay their social contribution, and they make life harder for workers, who in turn are less productive, leading to an inefficient economy. Rent seekers also contribute to the misallocation of labor in sectors by teaming up with international capital under the framework of globalization. Rent seekers are quick to move their operations overseas, stranding workers without high-skill jobs, then team up the government to prevent collective bargaining or a social safety net, causing either high unemployment or lower wages and less job security. Rent seeking also contributes to worker anxiety over affording basic needs and raising their families without access to education, healthcare, and other government programs. Consequently, their productivity goes down, which contributes to an inefficient economy.

The Key Problem in the Economy Is Demand

In contrast to thought from the political right, Stiglitz argues that too little demand is causing our economic problems, not insufficient supply. This difference lies at the heart of political debates about the budget, about austerity, about funding entitlement programs like Social Security, and about combatting inequality.

The supply-side argument is straightforward and was popularized by President Reagan in the 1980s as the trickle-down theory. The argument then, and now, is that if the top 1 percent are given tax savings and government transfers (in the form of monopolies, like intellectual property rights for new drugs, for example), they will produce more, and their production will trickle down to the rest of society, and the entire society will be wealthier. Stiglitz of course rejects this idea, but his reasons tie into a larger debate about what kind of society the United States wants: people who by and large make money off the backs of others, or people who work hard in sectors like manufacturing or mining or farming.

More importantly, Stiglitz believes that the 1 percent contribute to the demand problem because they take from the poor to enrich themselves. That transfer of money creates a demand problem that requires resources to be redistributed so that the poor can survive, the middle class can thrive, and all can stay in the game.

blurred text
blurred text
blurred text
blurred text