logo

77 pages 2 hours read

G. Edward Griffin

The Creature from Jekyll Island: A Second Look at the Federal Reserve

Nonfiction | Book | Adult | Published in 1994

A modern alternative to SparkNotes and CliffsNotes, SuperSummary offers high-quality Study Guides with detailed chapter summaries and analysis of major themes, characters, and more.

Part 2Chapter Summaries & Analyses

Part 2: “A Crash Course on Money”

Part 2, Chapter 7 Summary: “The Barbaric Metal”

Griffin argues that the definition of money has been intentionally confused by those in power. Therefore, his goal in this chapter is to demystify the concept of money and offer a functional definition. He distills various concepts of money into one working definition: “money is anything which is accepted as a medium of exchange” (142).

Griffin gives a brief history of barter and exchange to show how money evolved within human society. In barter economies, people exchanged items that had intrinsic value for other items with intrinsic value. Then came commodity money, in which items that everyone wants, like food, store value that can then be traded. With the advent of metal mining, metal became the most common commodity of money. Metal is ideal money because it is inherently valuable, can be broken down into smaller pieces for smaller purchases, is reliably measurable, is limited in supply, and is non-perishable. Initially, gold, silver, and copper were the primary units of money used throughout the world. All three are easy to transport and separable, and determining their purity and weight is reliable and simple.

In this system, the overall supply of money is unimportant because prices will adjust based on the currently available supply of money. Further, gold is still plentiful while remaining finite, which is an important aspect of effective currency. Griffin uses a game of Monopoly as an example to demonstrate that the amount of currency in the market makes prices higher or lower, but it doesn’t change the value associated with those prices.

Griffin argues that government intervention can and does destabilize currency through dilution of currency. Debasing currency, which is the term for any action that damages the intrinsic value of money, was a common practice throughout history. As an example, Griffin compares the strictly protected currency of Byzantium with the government-manipulated money of Ancient Rome. While Byzantium’s laws protected the standards of weight and honesty of bankers, Rome sought to increase currency. Griffin attributes the success of the Byzantine Empire in large part to its reliable currency. Rome’s fall, he claims, was caused by financial instability.

Griffin explains the origin of paper money, or receipt money. Goldsmiths who minted coins and bars had secure vaults. Individuals would pay the goldsmith a fee to store their coins, and the smith would issue a receipt that served as proof of ownership and amount. Over time, the receipts, representing the gold, were exchanged in place of the coin itself. Importantly, the receipt money had no intrinsic value; its value was in the gold it represented.

Griffin ends with a second law of human society: that the government’s power over money should be limited to protecting the honest quality of the currency akin to Byzantium to prevent economic disasters.

Part 2, Chapter 8 Summary: “Fool’s Gold”

Chapter 8 defines and explains fiat and fractional money. Fiat money is paper money decreed by the government to be money, which is not backed by gold or silver. Griffin describes the early American colonial experiments with fiat money, all of which resulted in economic disaster because of massive inflation. He focuses on how the return to gold and silver led to prosperity and economic stability, even under the pressure of war. Legal tender laws passed at the time of the American Revolution similarly created inflation and deflation cycles which the founders sought to eliminate in the Constitution by preventing the Federal Government from creating fiat money.

Griffin offers his third law: Fiat money leads to economic destruction.

Griffin now turns to fractional money, which he defines as money only partially backed by an intrinsically valuable tangible item. (The standard definition of “fractional money” is banknotes issued in units of less than one dollar.) The origin of banking and fractional money is identical: Goldsmiths who stored gold for a fee began to loan out the coin in their vaults for an interest charge. They would issue receipts to borrowers, just as to depositors, and those receipts would be exchanged in the marketplace as money. This form of banking is referred to as fractional reserve because the bankers only hold a fraction of the original deposits in their vaults, trusting that only a few people at a time will demand their money, and loan out the rest. Fractional money is an intermediary between receipt money fully backed by precious metals and fiat money not backed by precious metals.

This leads to Griffin’s closing with his fourth law: fractional money always becomes fiat money.

Part 2, Chapter 9 Summary: “The Secret Science”

Looking in more depth at banking history, Griffin relates the story of the Venetian bank established by the government which sustained itself solely through fees rather than interest. The bank was restricted from loaning money. When accepting a deposit, the bank would confirm with expertise the value of the deposited coin. As a result, the receipts from the Venetian bank were worth more in the marketplace than other receipts, or even coins, since the receipt value was reliable. This bank was put out of business by a government-created bank that had permission to loan money.

The Bank of England was given the responsibility of managing government-issued exchequer bills which were backed by the government’s gold stores. The Bank preferred its own banknotes and gradually those fractional bills replaced the government currency. Other banks were granted charters, but only the Bank of England was favored enough to be bailed out when close to failure. The reason for this favor was that the Bank was established to loan money to the government to avoid taxing the public during wartime. Because of fractional money, the bank was able to make private loans and earn interest from both types of loans. This relationship made the Bank of England the first central bank and the English government relied on the bank as much as the bank relied on the government. 

Part 2, Chapter 10 Summary: “The Mandrake Mechanism”

Griffin defines what he means when he says money is created out of nothing. In a fractional reserve system, money is created by lending. When the banker lends money to a borrower in a fractional reserve or fiat money system, new money is created and placed in the economy. All United States currency is fiat money. The Federal Reserve’s own publications clearly state that US currency cannot be exchanged for gold in the treasury. Federal Reserve Notes are not an asset, instead they are an IOU, and if all debts were paid there would be no money in circulation. The Federal Reserve has no desire to see all debts paid, as the primary function of the institution is to manage debt.

Griffin argues that debt is not necessarily a problem, but the banking system as it stands is morally if not legally fraudulent. The banks have no money of their own to lend and instead are lending money deposited by others. They charge interest to borrowers to create profit. Griffin believes that neither the depositor nor the borrower understands how the bank uses the money at their disposal. As a result, the banks make a profit, while the depositor assumes all the risk. Griffin argues that all bank loans under the fiat system are inherently usury, or excessive interest, because it’s unearned fiat money. Griffin argues that the profit the banks acquire is generated by human labor, but that profit stays with the bank rather than the laborers.

The Fed creates fiat money to purchase government bonds which they categorize as reserves. This created money enters the economy, through government spending and bank loans, which cause inflation. There are three methods the Fed uses to create money from IOUs or debt: the Discount Window, purchase of bonds, and adjusting the reserve ratio.

Banks use the Discount Window to shore up their assets if their reserves are depleted by a bank run, a currency drain, or other depleting event. The Fed then loans the bank money to bring their reserves to required levels at a relatively low interest rate. The banks can loan that money at a higher interest rate to make a profit and increase their assets on the books, which increases their reserves.

The primary method of money creation, though, is the buying and selling by the Fed of government bonds, which Griffin names the Mandrake Mechanism. The US government issues bonds—certificates that promise a specific payout on a given date—for sale on the bond market. The Fed purchases these bonds with a Federal Reserve Check which is deposited into the government’s account in the Federal Reserve. The money in that account is dispersed as government payments to individuals who deposit that money into their accounts at commercial banks.

The commercial bank is only required by the Fed to keep a certain number of deposits, currently 10%, as reserves, and so can lend out 90% of total deposits. The 90% of each deposit is considered excess reserves. That money enters the economy via bank loans. Those loans are then deposited in the borrower’s accounts, again allowing for additional loans of 90% of the deposited value. This process happens again and again until the new money entering the economy is up to 10 times the original debt issued by the Treasury. When that fiat money enters the economy, it drives prices up because there is more money in circulation which decreases the spending power of each dollar. That decrease in spending power is inflation. If the Fed sells rather than buys bonds, or borrowers pay off their debt and save rather than spend, prices will fall because the fiat money in the economy reduces. That cycle of prices rising then falling based on currency circulation, Griffin argues, causes the boom-and-bust cycle, because increasing amounts of currency in circulation (inflation) artificially stimulate the economy creating an economic bubble, while decreasing amounts of currency in circulation (deflation) contracts the economy which bursts the bubble.

Although federal debt and inflation are often connected, they are distinct and either can exist without the other. Federal debt in the form of bonds can be purchased by private citizens or corporations, and in that case, there is no money creation and no automatic inflation. Griffin says that eventually all the bonds bought by private entities with real money will come due, and the Fed will have to create fiat money to cover them.

The Fed can also create fiat money without buying government debt through the Discount Window by loaning money directly to banks. Additionally, the Fed can buy treasury bonds from other nations which use the money they receive to pay off interest on loans from American banks in the same process as US government bonds. The government need not be in debt for the Fed to create money. However, the Fed’s primary purpose is to ensure money is available for Congress to use at its discretion, and so the money in the US economy is generally dependent on US federal debt.

The inflation caused by the Fed’s money creation primarily negatively affects low- and middle-income Americans. As a result, Griffin says it is a tax that is both invisible and unfair and that is a fourth reason to abolish the Fed and the system it perpetuates. Griffin contends that this “tax” is so large that it has negated the necessity for direct tax income for the Federal government. However, taxes remain in place for two reasons: to avoid public curiosity about inflation and to serve social planning.

Part 2 Analysis

Throughout the book, Griffin offers “Laws” of human nature and “Reasons” to abolish the Federal Reserve. These are blocked off in their own mini-sections within chapters. In addition to these sections, Griffin offers a summary of his “Reasons” at the end of the preface and his “Laws” in Appendix B. These laws and reasons function as a summary of his primary argument. Similar to his previews and summaries, they allow readers to easily access Griffin’s points independent of discussions, anecdotes, and sources. They additionally focus the work on a primary argument that maintains the discussion of the Fed through sections that seem secondary or disconnected from the Fed itself.

In “The Mandrake Mechanism,” Griffin again employs multiple organizational approaches to increase accessibility. In addition to the specifically titled sections contained in all the chapters, “The Mandrake Mechanism” is placed apart by creating two charts. The first chart gives an overview of the Fed’s practices in one off-set paragraph. That form is followed up by a chart several pages later showing the progression of the Fed’s actions. Placing the Fed’s functionary mechanisms in a different form than the rest of the discussions in the book highlights its importance. It also gives readers a clear cause-and-effect image to follow to understand the most functional and important information to the primary purpose of the book.

Griffin’s argument that fraud is being legally perpetrated by the banks through lending and monetary policy is not a factual argument but a moral one. The overarching discussion of the gold standard and the history of currency highlights The Moral Implications of Fractional Reserve and Central Banking. FDR’s confiscation of privately held gold was an attempt to make it possible to produce more currency to help counteract the contraction of the economy after the crash of 1929, but the measure arguably harmed the purchasing power of private individuals. Griffin argues that this was not only unfair, a moral judgment, but led in later years to abandoning the gold standard not just in the US but throughout the world, which he sees as a bad thing. The story about the Venetian bank (the existence of which is disputed) which was put out of business by a fractional-reserve government bank frames the first bank as an honest institution destroyed by dishonest fractional-reserve lending. Griffin’s argument that all fractional-reserve banking is inherently usury is a contested one, not widely accepted among mainstream economists, but his examples point to problems that raise moral questions related to modern banking.

The Effect of Finance on Politics figures prominently in the history of money. The story of Byzantium and Rome provides an argument that politics can affect finance as fully as finance can affect government. Griffin claims that the success of Byzantium in contrast with the fall of Rome demonstrates that the financial health of a nation and the health of the government are innately connected. Fiat money can only seriously impact the economy if it is protected by government. Griffin’s third and fourth laws argue that fractional-reserve banking leads to fiat money which leads to economic destruction connecting finance and politics at a foundational level. However, as in the first section, several key points of Griffin’s arguments are based on false or unreliable evidence. The causes of the Fall of Rome, for instance, are numerous and still hotly contested among historians. Although economic mismanagement may have been one factor, it is a major oversimplification of the very complicated, multi-century history of the downfall of the Roman Empire to assert that their monetary policy was the main or only cause (Wasson, Donald L. “Fall of the Western Roman Empire.” World History Encyclopedia, 12 Apr 2018). Similarly, though there are benefits and drawbacks to both the gold standard and fiat money systems, the overwhelming consensus among economists and economic historians is that the fiat system is preferable to the gold standard despite inflation because the gold standard historically results in greater volatility and greater adverse impacts for ordinary people (See: “Gold Standard.” Kent A. Clark Center for Global Markets, 12 Jan 2012; Whaples, Robert. “Where Is There Consensus Among American Economic Historians? The Results of a Survey on Forty Propositions.” The Journal of Economic History, 3 Mar 2009; Dierks, Anthony M., Jonathan Rawls, and Eric Sims. “Bury the Gold Standard? A Quantitative Exploration.” Working Paper No. 28015, National Bureau of Economic Research. Oct 2020).

blurred text
blurred text
blurred text
blurred text