56 pages • 1 hour read
Charles WheelanA modern alternative to SparkNotes and CliffsNotes, SuperSummary offers high-quality Study Guides with detailed chapter summaries and analysis of major themes, characters, and more.
The free market system is the bedrock upon which economics is based, so it comes as no surprise that the author is in favor of free and open markets. While they cannot do everything and do some things poorly, in general, free markets make the best use of scarce resources. Since all resources are limited, we must use them efficiently to get the most out of them. Markets do this without regard to morals, values, politics, or other human concerns. In that way they can seem ruthless or heartless, but markets exist only to efficiently allocate resources. Wheelan makes it clear that we can certainly choose to prioritize morality and value judgments, but they will alter the market somehow.
The market system is covered explicitly in Chapter 1, but it really permeates the whole book. When Wheelan writes about government and international trade, for example, markets are still front and center. Chapter 4 explains how government action can reduce efficiency through excessive regulation. This is shown in the study that examined various countries’ rules for establishing new businesses. In poor countries, the number of steps and the costs are much higher than in developed countries. This impedes on the market, distorting it and reducing economic growth.
On the other hand, Chapter 3 has examples of when government provides really the only option for certain things. Climate change is the largest and most pressing of these issues. While markets use resources efficiently, this doesn’t mean they have no ill effects. Pollution is one byproduct, and there is no market incentive to avoid it. Because we value a world with less pollution, only government has the authority and resources to step in and impose limits. This is what Wheelan means when he writes we can prioritize certain values over unhindered markets.
International trade is an area that has gotten a lot of attention in recent years. More Americans seem to view it as a bad thing, as some jobs have moved from the United States to developing countries like Mexico and China. The Trump administration engaged in a trade war with China, slapping tariffs on a wide range of goods during the four years that Donald Trump was president. However, at every turn in the book, Wheelan makes it clear why he is opposed to this viewpoint and in favor of free trade between countries. He states that most all economists agree that free international trade improves the lives of people in all the countries involved. That said, there are people who do lose out. Wheelan acknowledges this and argues that governments have a responsibility to help them through financial assistance and retraining.
Another main theme of the book is that incentives matter. This is actually the title of Chapter 2, which covers incentives extensively, but they factor into everything else Wheelan writes about. They stem from self-interest (which is not the same as selfishness) and seeking utility. Get the incentives right, Wheelan argues, and you can guide people’s behavior. The word “guide” is more accurate than “control” here because one size does not fill all. People in different countries react to different incentives based on culture and level of economic well-being. Even within the lifespan of the same person, evolving priorities may change which incentives they respond to. Likewise, incentives might not seem obvious. They’re not just about money, and human behavior is complicated (people sometimes act against their own self-interest). That last point is something economists have learned more recently. People don’t act as rationally as previously assumed. Understanding this and taking it into account when devising incentives is important to getting the desired outcomes.
Incentives are difficult to get right. Sometimes they even worsen the problem they are set up to solve. One example Wheelan gives is the initiative during the Clinton administration to require the use of car seats for infants traveling in airplanes. On the face of it, this seemed to make sense. Car seats were required for use in automobiles, and they offer a more secure location than their parents’ arms in the event of an accident. However, they also required that another seat be purchased, which Wheelan explains made air travel too expensive for some. If a number of families decided to drive to their destination rather than fly, that would defeat the original purpose of increasing safety, because flying is much safer than driving. The incentive backfired.
Incentives are not just relevant to economic matters; they can be used to deal with important social issues as well. As Wheelan writes, “Our best hope for improving the human condition is to understand why we act the way we do and then plan accordingly” (56). An example covered in Chapter 5 is gender discrimination in the workplace. Wheelan explains that businesses are at a disadvantage in hiring because they don’t know the plans of their prospective employees. Because women will need to take time off if they decide to have a baby and because mothers are still much more likely than fathers to quit working in order to care for children, employers find it wiser to choose men over women when hiring. A simple solution, according to Wheelan, is to change the incentives: make maternity packages refundable. If a woman returns to her job after having a baby, she keeps the benefits; if she resigns to raise a family, she returns the benefits to the company.
Throughout the book, Wheelan makes it clear that we can choose the kind of economy and society we want. The free market alone will tend to go in one direction and result in one version of that world. However efficient that may be as a method of allocating resources, it’s only one option. We may choose to prioritize different things than merely efficiency or may have a vision of what kind of world we want to live in. By using government intervention and the right incentives, we can work toward putting that vision into practice.
This is most directly stated in the Epilogue, where one of Wheelan’s eight questions about life in the future is “Will we have strip malls in 2050?” (329). Strip malls may present an efficient way of shopping, but we may decide to create, say, bucolic areas of small shops because they’re more aesthetically pleasing and a more satisfying way to shop. At various other points in the book, however, the author also reminds readers that this kind of choice is always an option.
Income inequality is something Wheelan touches on more than once regarding this. For example, when discussing government intervention in Chapter 4, Wheelan writes that having a strong social safety net requires high taxes that will cut into economic growth. He compares the US to France, noting that the former opts more for growth while the latter opts for a stronger safety net. Neither is right or wrong; it all depends on how we want to live.
That said, Wheelan stresses that distorting the market through government action and other tools has its costs, and we must always be aware of what those costs are. We also have to be careful that one group does not impose its will on another by using political power. Finally, those who benefit the most should bear most of the costs.